TheEconomist: Diagnosticando la Depresión: diferencias entre recesión y depresión.

Fraga II

Madmaxista
Desde
10 Ago 2008
Mensajes
4.511
Reputación
4.179
Lugar
Spanish Great Depression
When jobs disappear | The Economist


Unemployment
When jobs disappear

Mar 12th 2009 | LONDON, TOKYO AND WASHINGTON, DC
From The Economist print edition




The world economy faces the biggest rise in unemployment in decades. How governments react will shape labour markets for years to come






LAST month America’s unemployment rate climbed to 8.1%, the highest in a quarter of a century. For those newly out of a job, the chances of finding another soon are the worst since records began 50 years ago. In China 20m migrant workers (maybe 3% of the labour force) have been laid off. Cambodia’s textile industry, its main source of exports, has cut one worker in ten. In Spain the building bust has pushed the jobless rate up by two-thirds in a year, to 14.8% in January. And in Japan, where official unemployment used to be all but unknown, tens of thousands of people on temporary contracts are losing not just their jobs but also the housing provided by their employers.

The next phase of the world’s economic downturn is taking shape: a global jobs crisis. Its contours are only just becoming clear, but the severity, breadth and likely length of the recession, together with changes in the structure of labour markets in both rich and emerging economies, suggest the world is about to undergo its biggest increase in unemployment for decades.


In the last three months of 2008 America’s GDP slumped at an annualised rate of 6.2%. This quarter may not be much better. Output has shrunk even faster in countries dependent on exports (such as Germany, Japan and several emerging Asian economies) or foreign finance (notably central and eastern Europe). The IMF said this week that global output will probably fall for the first time since the second world war. The World Bank expects the fastest contraction of trade since the Depression.

An economic collapse on this scale is bound to hit jobs hard. In its latest quarterly survey Manpower, an employment-services firm, finds that in 23 of the 33 countries it covers, companies’ hiring intentions are the weakest on record (see chart 1). Because changes in unemployment lag behind those in output, jobless rates would rise further even if economies stopped contracting today. But there is little hope of that. And several antiestéticatures of this recession look especially harmful.





The credit crunch has exacerbated the impact of falling demand, pressing cash-strapped firms to cut costs more quickly. The asset bust and unwinding of debt that lie behind the recession miccionan that eventual recovery is likely to be too weak to create jobs rapidly. And when demand does revive, the composition of jobs will change. In a post-bubble world indebted consumers will save more and surplus economies, from China to Germany, will have to rely more on domestic spending. The booming industries of recent years, from construction to finance, will not bounce back. Millions of people, from Wall Street bankers to Chinese migrants, will need to find wholly different lines of work.

For now the damage is most obvious in America, where the recession began earlier than elsewhere (in December 2007, according to the National Bureau of Economic Research) and where the ease of hiring and firing means changes in the demand for workers show up quickly in employment rolls. The economy began to lose jobs in January 2008. At first the decline was fairly modest and largely confined to construction (thanks to the housing bust) and manufacturing (where employment has long been in decline). But since September it has accelerated and broadened. Of the 4.4m jobs lost since the recession began, 3.3m have gone in the past six months. Virtually every sector has been hit hard. Only education, government and health care added workers last month.

So far, the pattern of job losses in this recession resembles that of the early post-war downturns (starting in 1948, 1953 and 1957). Those recessions brought huge, but temporary, swings in employment, in an economy far more reliant on manufacturing than today’s. As a share of the workforce, more jobs have been lost in this recession than in any since 1957. The pace at which people are losing their jobs, measured by the share of the workforce filing for weekly jobless claims, is much quicker than in the downturns of 1990 and 2001 (see chart 2).





The worry, however, is that the hangover from excess debt and the housing bust will miccionan a slow revival—looking more like the jobless recoveries after the past two downturns than like the vigorous V-shaped rebounds from the early post-war recessions. Ominous signs are a sharp increase in permanent-job losses and a rise in the number of people out of work for six months or more to 1.9% of the labour force, near a post-war high.

Official forecasts can barely keep up. In its budget in February the Obama administration expected a jobless rate of 8.1% for the year. That figure was reached within the month. Many Wall Street seers think the rate will exceed 10% by 2010 and may surpass the post-1945 peak of 10.8%. Past banking crises indicate an even gloomier prognosis. A study by Carmen Reinhart of the University of Maryland and Ken Rogoff of Harvard University suggests that the unemployment rate rose by an average of seven percentage points after other big post-war banking busts. That implies a rate for America of around 12%.

Moreover, the official jobless rate understates the amount of slack by more than in previous downturns. Many companies are cutting hours to reduce costs. At 33.3 hours, the average working week is the shortest since at least 1964. Unpaid leave is becoming more common, and not only at the cyclical manufacturing firms where it is established practice. A recent survey by Watson Wyatt, a firm of consultants, finds that almost one employer in ten intends to shorten the work week in coming months. Compulsory unpaid leave is planned by 6% of firms. Another 9% will have voluntary leave.

Europe’s jobs markets look less dire, for now. That is partly because the recession began later there, partly because joblessness had been unusually low by European standards and partly because Europe’s less flexible labour markets react more slowly than America’s. The euro area’s unemployment rate was 8.2% in January, up from 7.2% a year before. That of the whole European Union was 7.6%, up from 6.8%. For the first time in years American and European jobless rates are roughly in line (see chart 3).





Within the EU there are big variations. Ireland and Spain, where construction boomed and then subsided most dramatically, have already seen heavy job losses. Almost 30% of Ireland’s job growth in the first half of this decade came from the building trade. Its unemployment rate has almost doubled in the past year. In Britain, another post-property-bubble economy, the rate is also rising markedly. At the end of last year 6.3% of workers were jobless, up from 5.2% the year before. Figures due on March 18th are likely to show unemployment above 2m for the first time in more than a decade.

In continental Europe’s biggest economies, the consequences for jobs of shrivelling output are only just becoming visible. Although output in Germany fell at an annualised rate of 7% in the last quarter of 2008, unemployment has been only inching up. The rate is still lower than it was a year ago. Even so, no one doubts the direction in which joblessness is heading. In January the European Commission forecast the EU’s jobless rate to rise to 9.5% in 2010. As in America, many private-sector economists expect 10% or more.

Structural changes in Europe’s labour markets suggest that jobs will go faster than in previous downturns. Temporary contracts have proliferated in many countries, as a way around the expense and difficulty of firing permanent workers. Much of the reduction in European unemployment earlier this decade was due to the rapid growth of these contracts. Now the process is going into reverse. In Spain, Europe’s most extreme example of a “dual” labour market, all the job loss of the past year has been borne by temps. In France employment on temporary contracts has fallen by a fifth. Permanent jobs have so far been barely touched.

Although the profusion of temporary contracts has brought greater flexibility, it has laid the burden of adjustment disproportionately on the low-skilled, the young and immigrants. The rising share of immigrants in Europe’s workforce also makes the likely path of unemployment less certain. As Samuel Bentolila, an economist at CEMFI, a Spanish graduate school, points out, the jump in Spain’s jobless rate is not due to fewer jobs alone. Thanks to continued immigration, the labour force is still growing apace. In Britain, in contrast, hundreds of thousands of migrant Polish workers are reckoned to have gone home.

Despite having few immigrants, Japan is also showing the strains of a dual labour market. Indeed, its workforce is more starkly divided than that of any other industrial country. “Regular” workers enjoy strong protection; the floating army of temporary, contract and part-time staff have almost none. Since the 1990s, the “lost decade”, firms have relied increasingly on these irregulars, who now account for one-third of all workers, up from 20% in 1990.

As Japanese industry has collapsed, almost all the jobs shed have been theirs. Most are ineligible for unemployment assistance. A labour-ministry official estimates that a third of the 160,000 who have lost work in recent months have lost their homes as well, sometimes with only a few days’ notice. Earlier this year several hundred homeless temporary workers set up a tent village in Hibiya Park in central Tokyo, across from the labour ministry and a few blocks from the Imperial Palace. Worse lies ahead. Overall unemployment, now 4.1%, is widely expected to surpass the post-war peak of 5.8% within the year. In Japan too, some economists talk of double digits.

In emerging economies the scale of the problem is much harder to gauge. Anecdotal evidence abounds of falling employment, particularly in construction, mining and export-oriented manufacturing. But official figures on both job losses and unemployment rates are squishier. Estimates from the International Labour Organisation suggest the number of people unemployed in emerging economies rose by 8m in 2008 to 158m, an overall jobless rate of around 5.9%. In a recent report the ILO projected several scenarios for 2009. Its gloomiest suggested there could be an additional 32m jobless in the emerging world this year. That estimate now seems all too plausible. Millions will return from formal employment to the informal sector and from cities to rural areas. According to the World Bank, another 53m people will be pushed into extreme poverty in 2009.

History implies that high unemployment is not just an economic problem but also a political tinderbox. Weak labour markets risk fanning xenophobia, particularly in Europe, where this is the first downturn since immigration soared. China’s leadership is terrified by the prospect of social unrest from rising joblessness, particularly among the urban elite.

Given these dangers, politicians will not sit still as jobs disappear. Their most important defence is to boost demand. All the main rich economies and most big emerging ones have announced fiscal stimulus packages.

Since most emerging economies lack broad unemployment insurance, the main way they help the jobless is through labour-intensive government infrastructure projects as well as conditional cash transfers for the poorest. China’s fiscal boost includes plenty of money for infrastructure; India is accelerating projects worth 0.7% of GDP. However, a few emerging economies have more creative unemployment-insurance schemes than anything in the rich world. In Chile and Colombia formal-sector workers pay into individual unemployment accounts, on which they can draw if they lose their jobs. Many more countries have created prefunded pension systems based on individual accounts. Robert Holzmann of the World Bank thinks people should be allowed to borrow from such accounts while unemployed. Several countries are considering the idea.

In developed countries, governments’ past responses to high unemployment have had lasting and sometimes harmful effects. When joblessness rose after the 1970s oil shocks, Europe’s governments, pressed by strong trade unions, kept labour markets rigid and tried to cut dole queues by encouraging early retirement. Coupled with generous welfare benefits this resulted in decades of high “structural” unemployment and a huge rise in the share of people without work. In America, where the social safety net was flimsier, there were far fewer regulatory rigidities and people were more willing to move, so workers responded more flexibly to structural shifts. Less than six years after hitting 10.8%, the post-war record, in 1982, America’s jobless rate was close to 5%.



Policy in America still leans towards keeping benefits low and markets flexible rather than easing the pain of unemployment. Benefits for the jobless are, if anything, skimpier than in the 1970s. Unemployment insurance is funded jointly by states and the federal government. The states set the eligibility criteria and in many cases have not kept up with changes in the composition of the workforce. In 32 states, for instance, part-time workers are ineligible for benefits. All told, fewer than half of America’s unemployed receive assistance. The benefits they get also vary a lot from state to state, but overall are among the lowest in the OECD when compared with the average wage.

America’s recent stimulus package strengthened this safety net. Jobless benefits have increased modestly, their maximum duration has been extended, and states have been given a large financial incentive to broaden eligibility. The package also includes temporary subsidies to help pay for laid-off workers’ health insurance. Even so, benefits remain meagre.

Housing is a far bigger drag on American job mobility. Almost a fifth of American households with mortgages owe more than their house is worth, and house prices are set to fall further. “Negative equity” can lock in homeowners, making it hard to move to a new job. A recent study suggests that homeowners with negative equity are 50% less mobile than others.

Europe’s governments, at least so far, are trying hard to avoid the mistakes of the 1970s and 1980s. As Stefano Scarpetta of the OECD points out, today’s policies are designed to keep people working rather than to encourage them to leave the labour force. Several countries, from Spain to Sweden, have temporarily cut social insurance contributions to reduce labour costs.

A broader group including Austria, Denmark, France, Germany, Hungary, Italy and Spain, are encouraging firms to shorten work weeks rather than lay people off, by topping up the pay of workers on short hours. Germany, for instance, has long had a scheme that covers 60% of the gap between shorter hours and a full-time wage for up to six months. The government recently simplified the required paperwork, cut social-insurance contributions for affected workers, and extended the scheme’s maximum length to 18 months.

Britain has taken a different tack. Rather than intervening to keep people in their existing jobs, it has focused on deterring long-term joblessness with a package of subsidies to encourage employers to hire, and train, people who have been out of work for more than six months.

Of all rich-country governments, Japan’s has flailed the most. Forced to confront the ugly reality of its labour market, it is trying a mixture of policies. Last year it proposed tax incentives for companies to turn temps into regular employees—a futile effort when profits are scarce and jobs being slashed. The agriculture ministry suggested sending the jobless to the hinterland to work on farms and fisheries. As Naohiro Yashiro, an economist at the International Christian University in Tokyo, puts it: “Although temporary and part-time workers are everywhere in Japan, they are thought to be a threat to employment practices and—like terrorists—have to be contained.”

Recently, a more ambitious strategy has emerged. The government is considering shortening the minimum work period for eligibility to jobless benefits. It is providing newly laid-off workers with six-month loans for housing and living expenses. It is paying small-business owners to allow fired staff to remain in company dorms. It is subsidising the salaries of workers on mandatory leave. It is paying firms for rehiring laid-off staff, and offering grants to anyone willing to start a new business.

Whether these policies will be enough depends on how the downturn progresses. For by and large they are sticking-plasters, applied in the hope that the recession will soon be over and the industrial restructuring that amows will be modest. Subsidising shorter working weeks, for instance, props up demand today, but impedes long-term reordering. The inequities of a dual labour market will become more glaring the higher unemployment rises. Politicians seem to be hoping for the best. Given the speed at which their economies are deteriorating, they would do better to plan for the worst.
 

Halfredico

Madmaxista
Desde
10 Oct 2008
Mensajes
1.267
Reputación
862
"Arcarde dame una caza"

Editado por equivocacion
 
Última edición:

Fraga II

Madmaxista
Desde
10 Ago 2008
Mensajes
4.511
Reputación
4.179
Lugar
Spanish Great Depression
IMF warns over parallels to Great Depression - Telegraph



IMF warns over parallels to Great Depression



The International Monetary Fund has warned of "worrisome parallels" between the current global crisis and the Great Depression, despite the unprecedented steps already taken by central banks and governments worldwide.



By Ambrose Evans-Pritchard, International Business Editor
Last Updated: 8:42PM BST 17 Apr 2009




This recession is likely to be "unusually long and severe, and the recovery sluggish," said the Fund, releasing two advance chapters from its World Economic Outlook. However, it warned there is a risk that it could spiral down into a full-blown slump unless further action is taken to stop "feedback effects" gathering force.

Dominique Strauss-Kahn, head of the IMF, said millions of people risk being pushed back into poverty as the economic storm ravages the most vulnerable countries. "The human consequences could be absolutely devastating. This is a truly global crisis, and nobody is escaping," he said.

"The free-fall in the global economy may be starting to abate, with a recovery emerging in 2010, but this depends crucially on the right policies being adopted today."

Mr Strauss-Kahn called for a urgent action to "cleanse banks" of toxic assets and for further fiscal stimulus beyond the 2pc of global GDP already agreed. The snag is that high-debt countries may have hit the limits already.

"The impact becomes negative for debt levels that exceed 60pc of GDP," said the Fund.

While no countries were named, this would raise questions about Japan, Germany, France, Italy and ultimately Britain and the US after their bank rescues.

The IMF said the US is at the epicentre of this crisis just as it was in the Depression, setting the two episodes apart from normal downturns. However, the risks are greater this time. "While the credit boom in the 1920s was largely spec*ific to the US, the boom during 2004-2007 was global, with increased leverage and risk-taking in advanced economies and many emerging economies. Levels of integration are now much higher than during the inter-war period, so US financial shocks have a larger impact," it said.

The IMF said the global financial system is still under acute stress, with output tumbling and inflation falling towards zero in key nations. "The risks of debt deflation have increased," it said.

Abrupt halts in capital flows can have "dire consequences" for emerging economies, it said. Eastern Europe has already suffered the effects, with a 17.6pc fall in industrial production in February. The region is highly vulnerable to the credit crunch since it owes more than 50pc of its GDP to Western banks.

Synchronised world recessions striking all major regions are "historically rare" events, the Fund said. They last one and a half times as long typical downturns, and are amowed by painfully slow recoveries.



















FT Alphaville » Blog Archive » IMF: “worrisome parallels” with the Great Depression




IMF: “worrisome parallels” with the Great Depression

Posted by Sam Jones on Apr 17 12:13.

The IMF has pre-released two chapters from its forthcoming World Economic Outlook.





The amowing excerpts rather put all the recent talk of green shoots into perspective. A few banking swallows do not a spring make. Quite the contrary. The IMF is now explicitly briefing of an economic catastrophe second, if not equal to, the Great Depression of 1929-33.



Emphasis ours.

The global economy is experiencing the deepest downturn in the post–World War II period, as the financial crisis rapidly spreads around the world. A large number of advanced economies have fallen into recession, and economies in the rest of the world have slowed abruptly. Global trade and financial flows are shrinking, while output and employment losses mount. Credit markets remain frozen as borrowers are engaged in a drawn-out deleveraging process and banks struggle to improve their financial health. Many aspects of the current crisis are new and unanticipated. Uniquely, the current disruption combines a financial crisis at the heart of the world’s largest economy with a global downturn.

… recessions associated with financial crises tend to be unusually severe and their recoveries typically slow. Similarly, globally synchronized recessions are often long and deep, and recoveries from these recessions are generally weak. Countercyclical monetary policy can help shorten recessions, but its effectiveness is limited in financial crises. By contrast, expansionary fiscal policy seems particularly effective in shortening recessions associated with financial crises and boosting recoveries. However, its effectiveness is a decreasing ******** of the level of public debt. These findings suggest the current recession is likely to be unusually long and severe and the recovery sluggish.



In fact, says the IMF, global downturns are typically one and a half times as long as typical recessions.

Most worrying though is the explicit comparison the IMF makes with the Great Depression - something even bearish commentators have skirted around so far for antiestéticar of being alarmist. The IMF lays it on the line:



A recession began in the United States in August 1929. A tightening of monetary policy during the previous year, aimed at stemming stock market speculation, is widely seen as the initial cause. The stock market crashed in October 1929, which prompted a sharp decline in consumption, partly because of increased uncertainty about future income.

The recession intensified and turned into a depression over the course of 1931–32. Pernicious feedback loops between the financial sector and the real economy emerged, leading to entrenched debt deflation and four waves of bank runs and failures between 1930 and 1933. Private consumption and investment contracted sharply.



and today:



Despite the differences in mechanics, the effects on the behavior of financial intermediaries are similar. Funding problems have led to balance sheet contraction (deleveraging), fire sales of assets (adding to downward pressure on prices), increased holdings of liquid assets, and decreased lending (or holdings of risky assets) as a share of total assets. Moreover, with today’s highly interconnected financial system, there has been gridlock because of network effects in a world of multiple trading and large gross positions. The ultimate effects of these financial factors on the real economy are similar in the two episodes.



The IMF explicitly warns that it antiestéticars debt deflation - the hallmark, according to US economist Irving Fisher of the Great Depression’s economics:



There is continued pressure on asset prices, lending remains constrained by financial sector deleveraging and widespread lack of confidence in financial intermediaries, financial shocks have affected real activity on a global scale , and inflation is decelerating rapidly and is likely to approach values close to zero in a number of countries. Moreover, declining activity is beginning to create feedback effects that affect the solvency of financial intermediaries, which risks of debt deflation have increased.



The IMF is clear: it really is all in the hands of the G20. The right policies will see recovery “in 2011″, the wrong ones… who knows.



This entry was posted by Sam Jones on Friday, April 17th, 2009 at 12:13 and is filed under Capital markets. Tagged with Great depression, IMF.



















Why this is just a recession, not a depression - MoneyWeek


Why this is just a recession, not a depression

Apr 16, 2009




Have we learned enough since the 1930s?



The things I keep hearing are "Are we going into the Next Great Depression?" and "Will this turn out to be a 'lost decade' like Japan?"

I call this the Great Recession today. But that's all it is...

The Great Depression in the 1930s was actually a downturn that became something much worse because of failed government policy.

What did the politicians do? They raised interest rates – tight money was wrong. They threw up protectionist legislation – that was wrong. They let the banks fail. And they raised taxes. The policy errors were horrific! Economic policy in the 1930s was like medicine in the Victorian age.


Hopefully we've learned a lot since then. We're not going to bleed the economy with leeches anymore.

Sure enough, we've avoided the major mistakes. Bernanke's taken interest rates to zero. No one's going to pass the Smoot-Hawley tariff act. (Although they put that "Buy America" provision in the stimulus bill, which was a mistake. And Obama says he's going to raise the top tax rates in 2011, which is not good, either. They're also spending a lot of money they don't need to spend, but that's just politics.)

Because we won't make the same policy mistakes, we won't see the Next Great Depression.

Then people say, "OK, so it won't be a Great Depression with 25% unemployment and breadlines and such. But what about Japan?"

It's a pretty scary comparison. Japan's Nikkei stock index peaked at over 39,000 in 1989. And a month ago, it bottomed under 8,000. So you're talking about an incredible, 20-year loss of around 80%.

That was in a way worse than the Great Depression. As bad as the Depression was, if you'd bought after the crash you were in good shape 20 years later. That's not true in Japan.

But there is a big difference between our situation and Japan's. What happened in Japanese real estate in the 1980s makes the US housing bubble look minor league.

Commercial property in the Ginza district of Tokyo was selling for $1 million per square meter. Residential property was also wildly inflated. Then it dropped every single year for 15 years. And yet, by 2004, Tokyo still had the most expensive real estate in the world. The starting point of Japan's downturn is beyond imagining here.

The second thing is, there was no political will in Japan to get things done. They let their banks go on, zombie-like, making more bad loans to bad debtors as if they were healthy. The authorities let it go on for such a long time. They didn't take the proactive moves they needed to take to save the economy.

So again, the current situation in the US is not like Japan's... because the starting point is not nearly as bad and the Japanese didn't have the political will to take the hard steps to get things done.

I think we've seen the worst of the credit crisis here in the US Although the economy is still not working the way it should, people can see that it's getting somewhat better, and it's only going to continue to get better.

People tell me they're in cash... To me, that's a antiestéticar reaction, not an investment posture. After taxes and inflation, you're earning negative "real" returns.

If you're totally in cash, you're basically saying, "I don't see any opportunities in any sector of any market anywhere in the world." Not just stocks, but bonds, metals, whatever. Are you really saying you don't see any opportunity anywhere?

I don't believe it!




This article was written by Alex Green for the free daily investment newsletter DailyWealth
 

Fraga II

Madmaxista
Desde
10 Ago 2008
Mensajes
4.511
Reputación
4.179
Lugar
Spanish Great Depression
Economics focus: The lessons of 1937 | The Economist



Economics focus
The lessons of 1937





Christina Romer is the chairwoman of Barack Obama's Council of Economic Advisers and a scholar of the Depression


Jun 18th 2009
From The Economist print edition



In a guest article, Christina Romer says policymakers must learn from the errors that prolonged the Depression








AT A recent congressional hearing I cautiously noted some “glimmers of hope” that the economy could stabilise and perhaps start to rebound later in the year. I was asked if this meant that we should cancel much of the remaining spending in the $787 billion American Recovery and Reinvestment Act. I responded that the expected recovery was both months away and predicated on Recovery Act spending ramping up greatly. Only later did it hit me that I should have told the story of 1937.

The recovery from the Depression is often described as slow because America did not return to full employment until after the outbreak of the second world war. But the truth is the recovery in the four years after Franklin Roosevelt took office in 1933 was incredibly rapid. Annual real GDP growth averaged over 9%. Unemployment fell from 25% to 14%. The second world war aside, the United States has never experienced such sustained, rapid growth.

However, that growth was halted by a second severe downturn in 1937-38, when unemployment surged again to 19% (see chart). The fundamental cause of this second recession was an unfortunate, and largely inadvertent, switch to contractionary fiscal and monetary policy. One source of the growth in 1936 was that Congress had overridden Mr Roosevelt’s veto and passed a large bonus for veterans of the first world war. In 1937, this fiscal stimulus disappeared. In addition, social-security taxes were collected for the first time. These factors reduced the deficit by roughly 2.5% of GDP, exerting significant contractionary pressure.






Also important was an accidental switch to contractionary monetary policy. In 1936 the Federal Reserve began to worry about its “exit strategy”. After several years of relatively loose monetary policy, American banks were holding large quantities of reserves in excess of their legislated requirements. Monetary policymakers antiestéticared these excess reserves would make it difficult to tighten if inflation developed or if “speculative excess” began again on Wall Street. In July 1936 the Fed’s board of governors stated that existing excess reserves could “create an injurious credit expansion” and that it had “decided to lock up” those excess reserves “as a measure of prevention”. The Fed then doubled reserve requirements in a series of steps. Unfortunately it turned out that banks, still nervous after the financial panics of the early 1930s, wanted to hold excess reserves as a cushion. When that excess was legislated away, they scrambled to replace it by reducing lending. According to a classic study of the Depression by Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz, the resulting monetary contraction was a central cause of the 1937-38 recession.

The 1937 episode provides a cautionary tale. The urge to declare victory and get back to normal policy after an economic crisis is strong. That urge needs to be resisted until the economy is again approaching full employment. Financial crises, in particular, tend to leave scars that make financial institutions, households and firms behave differently. If the government withdraws support too early, a return to economic decline or even panic could amow. In this regard, not only should we not prematurely stop Recovery Act spending, we need to plan carefully for its expiration. According to the Congressional Budget Office, the Recovery Act will provide nearly $400 billion of stimulus in the 2010 fiscal year, but just over $130 billion in 2011. This implies a fiscal contraction of about 2% of GDP. If all goes well, private demand will have increased enough by then to fill the gap. If that is not the case, broad policy support may need to be sustained somewhat longer.


Perhaps a more fundamental lesson is that policymakers should find constructive ways to respond to the natural pressure to cut back on stimulus. For example, the Federal Reserve’s balance-sheet has more than doubled during the crisis, drawing considerable attention. Monetary policymakers have made it clear that they believe continued monetary ease is appropriate. Moreover, the Fed’s credit programmes are to some degree self-eliminating: as demand for its special credit facilities shrinks, so will its balance-sheet. But now may also be a sensible time to grant the Fed additional tools to help its balance-sheet contract once the economy has recovered. Some have suggested that the Fed be authorised to issue debt, as many other central banks do. This would enhance its ability to withdraw excess cash from the financial system. Granting such additional tools now could provide confidence that the Fed will be able to respond to inflationary pressures, without it having to create that confidence by actually tightening prematurely.


Fiscal health check


Now is also the time to think about our long-run fiscal situation. Despite the large budget deficit President Obama inherited, dealing with the current crisis required increasing the deficit substantially. To switch to austerity in the immediate future would surely set back recovery and risk a 1937-like recession-within-a-recession. But many are legitimately concerned about the longer-term budget situation. That is why the president has laid out a plan to shrink the deficit he inherited by half and has repeatedly emphasised the need to reduce the long-term deficit and put the debt-to-GDP ratio on a declining trajectory. In this regard, health-care reform presents a golden opportunity. The fundamental source of long-run deficits is rising health-care expenditures. By coupling the expansion of coverage with reforms that significantly slow the growth of health-care costs, we can dramatically improve the long-run fiscal situation without tightening prematurely.

As someone who has written somewhat critically of the short-sightedness of policymakers in the late 1930s, I feel new humility. I can see that the pressures they were under were probably enormous. Policymakers today need to learn from their experiences and respond to the same pressures constructively, without derailing the recovery before it has even begun.
 

Fraga II

Madmaxista
Desde
10 Ago 2008
Mensajes
4.511
Reputación
4.179
Lugar
Spanish Great Depression
FDR's Lessons for Obama - The Legacy of F.D.R. - TIME




FDR's Lessons for Obama






F.D.R. aboard the U.S.S. Houston in July 1938.
Franklin D. Roosevelt Library




Alas for countless pundits and inspirational speakers, it is apparently not the case that the Chinese word for crisis is spelled by joining the characters for danger and opportunity. But that common fallacy nevertheless captures an important metaphorical truth: whatever the perils it brings with it, a crisis can be a grand opportunity. Among those who have understood that truth was Franklin D. Roosevelt.


Writing to his fellow Democrats in the 1920s, Roosevelt noted that their party could not hope to return to power until the Republicans led the nation "into a serious period of depression and unemployment." The Great Depression soon brought a far longer and deeper period of woe than F.D.R. foresaw. But the crisis of the 1930s also provided an object lesson in the relationship between economic danger and political opportunity — a lesson Barack Obama is now trying to amow. Obama, too, came to office in the midst of an economic crisis, and in the solutions he has offered, it appears he has often looked to the example of F.D.R., whose presidency — and the very idea of activist government that it represents — is very much back in the public mind this year. Roosevelt pushed through policies that aimed not just to deal with the immediate challenge of the Great Depression but also to benefit generations of Americans to come. Pulling off a similar antiestéticat will require Obama to persuade Americans to see opportunities in the present crisis as well.


A More Secure America


It's old news that F.D.R.'s New Deal did not end the Depression. On that score, there was little difference between Roosevelt and Herbert Hoover. But unlike Hoover, F.D.R. seized the occasion to shape a legacy of durable reforms. For that accomplishment — along with winning World War II — historians routinely rank him among the greatest Presidents.


So what did Roosevelt's greatness consist of, and how did he attain it?


Forget about the Hundred Days of 1933, the legendary crucible in which F.D.R.'s anti-Depression strategy was supposedly forged. The legislative frenzy of that fabled springtime gave a stricken nation a valuable psychological boost, but many of its initiatives did not survive the Depression decade. F.D.R.'s greatest achievements came later. Their essence can be summed up in a single word: security.


All the major New Deal reforms that endured had a common purpose: not simply to end the immediate crisis of the Depression but also to make America in the future a less risky place, to temper for generations thereafter what F.D.R. called the "hazards and vicissitudes" of life. By creating the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), the New Deal provided more confidence to bank depositors. With the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), it guaranteed more reliable information for investors. The Federal Housing Administration gave more protection to mortgage lenders and thus more options to home buyers. The National Labor Relations Board brought more stability to dealings between capital and labor. The Fair Labor Standards Act ensured more predictable wages for the most vulnerable workers. And Social Security offered at least a minimal safety net for both the unemployed and the elderly.


Those reforms constitute our most valuable heritage from the Depression era. Few of them generated any appreciable economic stimulus in the short run. But taken together, those measures laid the foundation for unprecedented economic growth and broadly shared prosperity in the years after World War II — an era that the novelist Philip Roth once aptly described as "the greatest moment of collective inebriation in American history."



A Postwar Roosevelt Boom


Roosevelt's innovations dramatically changed the character of American society. They deeply shaped the life trajectory of the so-called Greatest Generation, as well as the fates of millions born well after the Depression passed. It was no coincidence that African-American aspirations for full citizenship, denied for a century, were substantially realized at last in that context of stable economic health and almost giddy national self-confidence. By any conceivable metric, the New Deal's reforms were a success, as gauged by the conspicuous upward social mobility of several postwar generations of both genders and all races and ethnicities.


With the exception of the FDIC, however, none of them dates from the Hundred Days, or even from 1933. Therein lies an important lesson. Had the Hundred Days swiftly brought about economic recovery, a return to business as usual might have meant politics as usual as well. In that scenario it is doubtful that any of those landmark reforms would have come to pass. Roosevelt, in short, understood the difference between the urgent and the important. He could hardly ignore the compelling need to steer the economy out of the Depression, but he refused to allow that task to deflect him from his more important objective of making American life less hazardous — and more inclusive — ever after. He aimed not merely to end the crisis at hand but to forestall similar calamities in the future, and thereby to build a country, as he once said, "in which no one is left out."



F.D.R. appreciated the irony that it was the Depression that made it possible for him to realize those larger objectives. It would be too much to say that he deliberately prolonged the crisis to preserve the possibilities for reform. But he candidly acknowledged the relationship between peril and progress in his second Inaugural Address, on Jan. 20, 1937. He began on that day by boasting of "our progress out of the Depression" and went on to list several signs of returning prosperity.

But then he said something decidedly unusual in the canon of presidential addresses. "Such symptoms of prosperity," he warned, "may become portents of disaster!" Only then did he utter one of his most quoted and most misunderstood lines: "I see one-third of a nation ill housed, ill clad, ill nourished."

The address in its entirety makes it clear that when he spoke of that "one-third of a nation," F.D.R. was not referring primarily to the victims of the Great Depression, which he thought was ending. He was speaking, rather, about the accumulated social and human deficits spawned by more than a century of buccaneering, laissez-faire American capitalism — deficits that he considered not yet fully redeemed in 1937. Solving that problem was what he meant when he said in June 1936 that "this generation of Americans has a rendezvous with destiny."

Such rendezvous are rare in American history, and not without reason. As the historian Henry Adams wrote, among the founders of the Republic, the greatest antiestéticar "was power; not merely power in the hands of a president or a prince, of one assembly or several, of many citizens or few, but power in the abstract, wherever it existed and under whatever form it was known." That's why the framers of the Constitution constructed a political order based on "checks and balances." That arrangement has conspicuous virtues, but it also designs a measure of paralysis into the American political system. It impedes swift adjustment to changing economic and social realities. It sustains a chronic deadlock in which trauma and shock become the necessary preconditions for effective political action. To a degree not found in other political cultures, it forges a perverse partnership between danger and opportunity.

President Obama knows this. Asked by PBS news anchor Jim Lehrer in February if he did not feel burdened by the several crises now besetting the country, Obama noted that the moment "is full of peril but full of possibility" and that such times are "when the political system starts to move effectively."

Roosevelt could not have said it better. F.D.R. championed a long-deferred reform agenda that put security at its core. Obama wants to advance another set of reforms that have long been stalled. He has already used the crisis to propose new regulatory rules for the banking-and-finance industry. But there are many more objectives on the horizon. Universal health care was first advocated in the platform of Theodore Roosevelt's Progressive Party in 1912. A cogent energy policy has been pushed by every President since Richard Nixon, to no avail. Immigration begs for comprehensive rethinking, as do education, a host of environmental issues, and central tenets of national-security policy and military doctrine.

Like F.D.R., Obama must take measures to turn the economy around. If he doesn't, he'll go down in the history books as another Hoover. But to warrant comparison with Roosevelt, he will be judged not simply on whether he manages a rescue from the current economic crisis but also on whether he grasps the opportunity to make us more resilient to face those future crises that inevitably await us.





Kennedy teaches history at Stanford University. He is the author of Freedom from antiestéticar: The American People in Depression and War, 1929-1945, which won the 2000 Pulitzer Prize for history





















El titular de este artículo parece un sarcasmo:



G20 saved world from depression: Keating





G20 saved world from depression: Keating

July 2, 2009

The convening of the group of 20 (G20) nations has saved the world from "the horrendous effects of a second depression", former prime minister Paul Keating says.

Mr Keating, delivering the John Curtin Prime Ministerial Lecture at Perth's Curtin University on Thursday, said the G20 had transformed the world from being run in a "completely unrepresentative way" by the group of seven (G7).

Mr Keating said the G7 had collectively been a group of debtor states.

"Despite all that had happened in the post colonial history of the world amowing World War II, in places like India and China, continental Africa and South America, the conceit prevailed that the world could be run without reference to these places or to their interest," Mr Keating said.

He said the world had essentially been run by the victors of WWII with "outrider roles" for Germany and Japan.

Mr Keating said the G20 meetings had been held in an attempt to save the world from another depression.

"And time will show that timely action did save the world from the horrendous effects of a second depression," Mr Keating said.

He said the reconvened meeting of the G20 in London last April had "finally nailed the conceit" of the G7 nations.

"Now, the great surplus states like China sit at the head table, as do the large demographically young states like India and Brazil," he said.

"So finally, the world is being remade, to replace the unco-operative and unrepresentative structure I spoke of in this forum seven years ago."

Mr Keating said the "pendulum point of world economic activity" had shifted and settled on East Asia.

"It has settled, not with any particular comfort, but it has settled," Mr Keating said.

He said the global financial crisis had become the "second great international discontinuity" after the first, which was the end of the Cold War.

He said the crisis had forced the changes in international co-operation but said the crisis would give rise to a fundamental repair of the international trade and savings imbalance.

"Surplus countries like China, Russia and the oil states will have to save and consume more while deficit countries like the United States, Britain and Australia would have to save more and consume less," he said.

He said China would have to change its focus to domestic consumption with a focus on housing and services while the US would have to adapt to a greater emphasis on exports.

"These effects will promote profound changes in the character of employment and social development in these countries," Mr Keating said.

He said Australia too would have to save more and consume less and return to being a net export country, "earning our way out of our current account deficit imbalance".

"It is obvious that these two great discontinuities, the end of the Cold War and the global financial crisis, will change the way our own country fu.nct.ions as it must change the way we look at the world around us."
 
Última edición:

Fraga II

Madmaxista
Desde
10 Ago 2008
Mensajes
4.511
Reputación
4.179
Lugar
Spanish Great Depression
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/07/03/opinion/03krugman.html



Op-Ed Columnist
That ’30s Show




By PAUL KRUGMAN
Published: July 2, 2009





O.K., Thursday’s jobs report settles it. We’re going to need a bigger stimulus. But does the president know that?

Let’s do the math.

Since the recession began, the U.S. economy has lost 6 ½ million jobs — and as that grim employment report confirmed, it’s continuing to lose jobs at a rapid pace. Once you take into account the 100,000-plus new jobs that we need each month just to keep up with a growing population, we’re about 8 ½ million jobs in the hole.

And the deeper the hole gets, the harder it will be to dig ourselves out. The job figures weren’t the only bad news in Thursday’s report, which also showed wages stalling and possibly on the verge of outright decline. That’s a recipe for a descent into Japanese-style deflation, which is very difficult to reverse. Lost decade, anyone?

Wait — there’s more bad news: the fiscal crisis of the states. Unlike the federal government, states are required to run balanced budgets. And faced with a sharp drop in revenue, most states are preparing savage budget cuts, many of them at the expense of the most vulnerable. Aside from directly creating a great deal of misery, these cuts will depress the economy even further.

So what do we have to counter this scary prospect? We have the Obama stimulus plan, which aims to create 3 ½ million jobs by late next year. That’s much better than nothing, but it’s not remotely enough. And there doesn’t seem to be much else going on. Do you remember the administration’s plan to sharply reduce the rate of foreclosures, or its plan to get the banks lending again by taking toxic assets off their balance sheets? Neither do I.

All of this is depressingly familiar to anyone who has studied economic policy in the 1930s. Once again a Democratic president has pushed through job-creation policies that will mitigate the slump but aren’t aggressive enough to produce a full recovery. Once again much of the stimulus at the federal level is being undone by budget retrenchment at the state and local level.

So have we failed to learn from history, and are we, therefore, doomed to repeat it? Not necessarily — but it’s up to the president and his economic team to ensure that things are different this time. President Obama and his officials need to ramp up their efforts, starting with a plan to make the stimulus bigger.

Just to be clear, I’m well aware of how difficult it will be to get such a plan enacted.

There won’t be any cooperation from Republican leaders, who have settled on a strategy of total opposition, unconstrained by facts or logic. Indeed, these leaders responded to the latest job numbers by proclaiming the failure of the Obama economic plan. That’s ludicrous, of course. The administration warned from the beginning that it would be several quarters before the plan had any major positive effects. But that didn’t stop the chairman of the Republican Study Committee from issuing a statement demanding: “Where are the jobs?”

It’s also not clear whether the administration will get much help from Senate “centrists,” who partially eviscerated the original stimulus plan by demanding cuts in aid to state and local governments — aid that, as we’re now seeing, was desperately needed. I’d like to think that some of these centrists are feeling remorse, but if they are, I haven’t seen any evidence to that effect.

And as an economist, I’d add that many members of my profession are playing a distinctly unhelpful role.

It has been a rude shock to see so many economists with good reputations recycling old fallacies — like the claim that any rise in government spending automatically displaces an equal amount of private spending, even when there is mass unemployment — and lending their names to grossly exaggerated claims about the evils of short-run budget deficits. (Right now the risks associated with additional debt are much less than the risks associated with failing to give the economy adequate support.)

Also, as in the 1930s, the opponents of action are peddling scare stories about inflation even as deflation looms.

So getting another round of stimulus will be difficult. But it’s essential.

Obama administration economists understand the stakes. Indeed, just a few weeks ago, Christina Romer, the chairwoman of the Council of Economic Advisers, published an article on the “lessons of 1937” — the year that F.D.R. gave in to the deficit and inflation hawks, with disastrous consequences both for the economy and for his political agenda.

What I don’t know is whether the administration has faced up to the inadequacy of what it has done so far.

So here’s my message to the president: You need to get both your economic team and your political people working on additional stimulus, now. Because if you don’t, you’ll soon be facing your own personal 1937.
 

Fraga II

Madmaxista
Desde
10 Ago 2008
Mensajes
4.511
Reputación
4.179
Lugar
Spanish Great Depression
http://www.cotizalia.com/valor-anadido/crisis-siniestras-similitudes-depresion-20100509.html


La crisis y sus siniestras similitudes con la Gran Depresión






Me recordaba hace pocos días un interlocutor un tanto peculiar cómo la velocidad de circulación del dinero se había reducido en Estados Unidos a niveles no vistos en cerca de 70 años, esto es: desde la época de la Gran Depresión. Pocos elementos hay tan representativos para medir la recuperación de la confianza del/en el sector privado y la sanidad de un sistema bancario como éste, con su consecuente impacto en precios y/o producción, si atendemos a la teoría cuantitativa del dinero. El aumento de la masa monetaria, objetivo perseguido por los bancos centrales con sus bajadas de tipos de interés y medidas adicionales de quantitative easing, carece de impacto en la economía real si el multiplicador que la velocidad representa permanece deprimido. El exceso de apalancamiento en gran parte de las economías desarrolladas, por una parte, y la prevención de las entidades financieras ante la situación de su activo, las dificultades para financiar su pasivo y los nuevos requerimientos de solvencia, por otra, justificarían tal parálisis.

Los datos que mi acompañante manejaba eran de finales de febrero. Entonces, aunque ya se vislumbraban las dificultades soberanas que finalmente han aflorado con tanta virulencia, para muchos era difícil aventurar un desenlace como el vivido por los mercados financieros en la última semana, comportamiento similar al que se produjera cuando el colapso de Lehman Brothers. El elemento temporal es importante ya que la situación de inacción monetaria era ya previa a la más reciente coyuntura y revelaba una notable desconfianza en cualquier recuperación medianamente sólida. Aún así la propensión al riesgo por parte de los inversores siguió aumentando en la creencia de que lo peor había pasado. Nunca entenderé demasiado bien esa complacencia toda vez que, parece mentira, era hacía apenas veinte meses que el apocalipsis financiero llamaba a nuestra puerta. Escenas de pánico, por cierto, que se han vuelto a revivir esta semana como pone de manifiesto las muchas preguntas que un servidor ha recibido relacionadas con la posibilidad de un corralito o la efectividad de la garantía de depósitos establecida en España.

Estamos, por tanto, en una situación similar a la que se vivió a escala global después del Crack del 29. Un rebote bursátil importante que llevó a muchos políticos y analistas a proclamar el fin de la crisis, sólo para comprender poco después que no se trataba del principio del fin sino del final del principio. La atención se ha centrado en Grecia y en las naciones periféricas del Sur de Europa pero podía haber descansado igualmente en los países de Europa del Este, Japón –donde gran parte de la deuda está en manos domésticas y se ve compensada por el fuerte ahorro privado-, Reino Unido o Estados Unidos. La mayor economía del planeta se enfrenta a ingresos decrecientes, gastos al alza, un déficit presupuestario brutal con muchas de sus administraciones regionales y locales quebradas –que, por cierto, están siendo víctimas igualmente de los CDS-, un mercado de financiación municipal bajo enorme presión y así sucesivamente, ¿les suena de algo? Es el tuerto en el país de los ciegos, emergentes aparte. No se lleven a engaño. Los paralelismos con lo que aconteciera hace siete décadas son preocupantes, con dos peros que ahondan en tal percepción: actualmente la economía financiera es mucho más global que nunca, lo que facilita la difusión de sus dificultades, y el volumen que en ella se negocia es ingente hasta el punto del que sólo en el mercado de divisas se intercambian, diariamente, cuatro billones de dólares de los que el 37% tienen contrapartida en forma de euros. 1,48 billones diarios en la moneda única contra los que se pretende luchar con un fondo comunitario de… ¿100.000, 200.000 millones? David contra Goliat.

Más nos vale, por tanto, estar preparados para lo peor. No lo digo con ánimo derrotista sino desde el realismo más crudo. No se han querido aprender las imprescindibles lecciones del pasado y el resultado ha sido incurrir en los mismos errores. Ahora lo importante es tratar de evitar las penosas consecuencias que de ellos se derivaron y que concluyeron, más nos vale no olvidarlo, en una guerra mundial. Cuanto antes se produzca una toma de conciencia colectiva, mejor que mejor. Hora de trabajar el doble y cobrar la mitad. Pienso sinceramente que nos vemos abocados por la fuerza de los acontecimientos a una tierra de promisión, un lugar donde van a abundar las oportunidades para todos aquellos que sean capaces de navegar por las procelosas aguas de la crisis actual con naves bien diseñadas y preparadas. Se ha oído hasta la saciedad en los últimos meses el discurso de la necesidad de adaptación. Y, sin embargo, seguimos lamentándonos de lo todo aquello que no depende de nosotros y que es el medio en el que, sí o sí, nos hemos de desenvolver. El futuro siempre será oscuro como boca de lobo para que el que espera sentado a que sea otro el que le saque las castañas del fuego. Evitemos caer en esa tentación. Buena semana a todos.
 
Última edición:

Fraga II

Madmaxista
Desde
10 Ago 2008
Mensajes
4.511
Reputación
4.179
Lugar
Spanish Great Depression
Y es que los brotes verdes son ya un viejo invento:


Un rebote bursátil importante que llevó a muchos políticos y analistas a proclamar el fin de la crisis, sólo para comprender poco después que no se trataba del principio del fin sino del final del principio






http://www.burbuja.info/inmobiliari...aron-que-ya-se-acababa-la-gran-depresion.html



Para recordarnos que las cosas no han cambiado tanto, y que están intentando los mismos trucos. Lo mejor, el último.

1927-1933 Chart of Pompous Prognosticators - Print Version



1. "We will not have any more crashes in our time."
- John Maynard Keynes in 1927

2. "I cannot help but raise a dissenting voice to statements that we are living in a fool's paradise, and that prosperity in this country must necessarily diminish and recede in the near future."
- E. H. H. Simmons, President, New York Stock Exchange, January 12, 1928

"There will be no interruption of our permanent prosperity."
- Myron E. Forbes, President, Pierce Arrow Motor Car Co., January 12, 1928

3. "No Congress of the United States ever assembled, on surveying the state of the Union, has met with a more pleasing prospect than that which appears at the present time. In the domestic field there is tranquility and contentment...and the highest record of years of prosperity. In the foreign field there is peace, the goodwill which comes from mutual understanding."
- Calvin Coolidge December 4, 1928

4. "There may be a recession in stock prices, but not anything in the nature of a crash."
- Irving Fisher, leading U.S. economist , New York Times, Sept. 5, 1929

5. "Stock prices have reached what looks like a permanently high plateau. I do not feel there will be soon if ever a 50 or 60 point break from present levels, such as (bears) have predicted. I expect to see the stock market a good deal higher within a few months."
- Irving Fisher, Ph.D. in economics, Oct. 17, 1929

"This crash is not going to have much effect on business."
- Arthur Reynolds, Chairman of Continental Illinois Bank of Chicago, October 24, 1929

"There will be no repetition of the break of yesterday... I have no antiestéticar of another comparable decline."
- Arthur W. Loasby (President of the Equitable Trust Company), quoted in NYT, Friday, October 25, 1929

"We feel that fundamentally Wall Street is sound, and that for people who can afford to pay for them outright, good stocks are cheap at these prices."
- Goodbody and Company market-letter quoted in The New York Times, Friday, October 25, 1929

6. "This is the time to buy stocks. This is the time to recall the words of the late J. P. Morgan... that any man who is bearish on America will go broke. Within a few days there is likely to be a bear panic rather than a bull panic. Many of the low prices as a result of this hysterical selling are not likely to be reached again in many years."
- R. W. McNeel, market analyst, as quoted in the New York Herald Tribune, October 30, 1929

"Buying of sound, seasoned issues now will not be regretted"
- E. A. Pearce market letter quoted in the New York Herald Tribune, October 30, 1929

"Some pretty intelligent people are now buying stocks... Unless we are to have a panic -- which no one seriously believes, stocks have hit bottom."
- R. W. McNeal, financial analyst in October 1929

7. "The decline is in paper values, not in tangible goods and services...America is now in the eighth year of prosperity as commercially defined. The former great periods of prosperity in America averaged eleven years. On this basis we now have three more years to go before the tailspin."
- Stuart Chase (American economist and author), NY Herald Tribune, November 1, 1929

"Hysteria has now disappeared from Wall Street."
- The Times of London, November 2, 1929

"The Wall Street crash doesn't miccionan that there will be any general or serious business depression... For six years American business has been diverting a substantial part of its attention, its energies and its resources on the speculative game... Now that irrelevant, alien and hazardous adventure is over. Business has come home again, back to its job, providentially unscathed, sound in wind and limb, financially stronger than ever before."
- Business Week, November 2, 1929

"...despite its severity, we believe that the slump in stock prices will prove an intermediate movement and not the precursor of a business depression such as would entail prolonged further liquidation..."
- Harvard Economic Society (HES), November 2, 1929

8. "... a serious depression seems improbable; [we expect] recovery of business next spring, with further improvement in the fall."
- HES, November 10, 1929

"The end of the decline of the Stock Market will probably not be long, only a few more days at most."
- Irving Fisher, Professor of Economics at Yale University, November 14, 1929

"In most of the cities and towns of this country, this Wall Street panic will have no effect."
- Paul Block (President of the Block newspaper chain), editorial, November 15, 1929

"Financial storm definitely passed."
- Bernard Baruch, cablegram to Winston Churchill, November 15, 1929

9. "I see nothing in the present situation that is either menacing or warrants pessimism... I have every confidence that there will be a revival of activity in the spring, and that during this coming year the country will make steady progress."
- Andrew W. Mellon, U.S. Secretary of the Treasury December 31, 1929

"I am convinced that through these measures we have reestablished confidence."
- Herbert Hoover, December 1929

"[1930 will be] a splendid employment year."
- U.S. Dept. of Labor, New Year's Forecast, December 1929

10. "For the immediate future, at least, the outlook (stocks) is bright."
- Irving Fisher, Ph.D. in Economics, in early 1930

11. "...there are indications that the severest phase of the recession is over..."
- Harvard Economic Society (HES) Jan 18, 1930

12. "There is nothing in the situation to be disturbed about."
- Secretary of the Treasury Andrew Mellon, Feb 1930

13. "The spring of 1930 marks the end of a period of grave concern...American business is steadily coming back to a normal level of prosperity."
- Julius Barnes, head of Hoover's National Business Survey Conference, Mar 16, 1930

"... the outlook continues favorable..."
- HES Mar 29, 1930

14. "... the outlook is favorable..."
- HES Apr 19, 1930

15. "While the crash only took place six months ago, I am convinced we have now passed through the worst -- and with continued unity of effort we shall rapidly recover. There has been no significant bank or industrial failure. That danger, too, is safely behind us."
- Herbert Hoover, President of the United States, May 1, 1930

"...by May or June the spring recovery forecast in our letters of last December and November should clearly be apparent..."
- HES May 17, 1930

"Gentleman, you have come sixty days too late. The depression is over."
- Herbert Hoover, responding to a delegation requesting a public works program to help speed the recovery, June 1930

16. "... irregular and conflicting movements of business should soon give way to a sustained recovery..."
- HES June 28, 1930

17. "... the present depression has about spent its force..."
- HES, Aug 30, 1930

18. "We are now near the end of the declining phase of the depression."
- HES Nov 15, 1930

19. "Stabilization at [present] levels is clearly possible."
- HES Oct 31, 1931

20. "All safe deposit boxes in banks or financial institutions have been sealed... and may only be opened in the presence of an agent of the I.R.S."
- President F.D. Roosevelt, 1933
 

Fraga II

Madmaxista
Desde
10 Ago 2008
Mensajes
4.511
Reputación
4.179
Lugar
Spanish Great Depression
Desgraciadamente esto cada día se parece más a la Gran Depresión - Las Perlas de Kike - Cotizalia.com

Las Perlas de Kike, Kike Vázquez
Desgraciadamente esto cada día se parece más a la Gran Depresión



Todo empezó hace algo más de diez años, por aquel entonces por razones de demografía y expectativas de prosperidad la gente empezó a invertir en el mercado inmobiliario. Al principio la mayoría eran familias que buscaban un hogar, pero luego viendo la tendencia de subidas también se apuntaron muchos que compraban y vendían haciendo ganancias rápidas. El endeudamiento aumentaba vertiginosamente, pero a nadie parecía importarle ya que las empresas marcaban beneficios récord e incluso había quien insinuaba que habíamos pasado a una nueva era de bienestar a largo plazo.


El dinero no solo fluyó a la vivienda, también a los mercados financieros, tanto es así que la economía financiera iba desplazando poco a poco a la real a la vez que el apalancamiento iba desplazando a la sensatez. Fue bonito mientras duró, porque finalmente después de algún aviso la bolsa se desplomó estrepitosamente, de repente comprendimos que todo fue irreal y lo que queda es una pesada losa llamada deuda. El paro se disparó, aunque después de numerosas dificultades parece que poco a poco la situación va volviendo a su cauce y que con esfuerzo saldremos adelante. Ya pasaron unos meses desde el desplome y la bolsa ha repuntado de forma notoria, seguramente apuntando al inicio de la recuperación.


Firmado “Un ciudadano de EEUU”, 1930.




El texto lo podríamos firmar nosotros ahora, un irlandés, un estadounidense o alguien de los años 30, lo mismo da porque los síntomas son los mismos. Pero centrémonos en el mundo global de hoy en día y lo visto en la gran depresión, desgraciadamente los paralelismos son cada día mayores. ¿Habrá también ahora un repunte fruto de un espejismo para luego pasar a un prolongado estancamiento?

Sigamos comparando, en la Gran Depresión se llegó a una guerra comercial con aranceles proteccionistas, hoy por el momento nos quedamos en la guerra de divisas. Por aquel entonces se generó el caldo de cultivo a la WWII y hoy tenemos a ambas Coreas a un paso de "fundirse" o a EEUU armando a Arabia Saudí ante una eventual intervención para hacerse con el petróleo Iraní, en cualquier caso la industria bélica sale favorecida como ocurrió antes. Otras similitudes podemos encontrarlas en que en el 29 el apalancamiento era para invertir en bolsa, hoy es el día a día de las finanzas y por ejemplo el montante existente de derivados supera al PIB mundial. Si antes la economía ficticia desplazaba a la real ahora la ha barrido.

Comparen “antes” y “después” en deuda privada.





Pero no teman, hemos evolucionado, el mundo es distinto y no hay dos crisis iguales, principalmente porque ahora se ha actuado, hasta el momento, mejor (reducir la masa monetaria para incrementar los efectos de la caída sería difícil de justificar esta vez). Además hemos prosperado en sanidad, en innovación, en ciencia, en tecnología… el sistema monetario es un fraude, pero al menos ha conseguido crear algo bueno a lo que agarrarse. Es decir, tenemos por una parte algo nefasto, un sistema que ha generado deudas que no sabemos cómo podremos pagar y por la otra algo positivo, algo que sin esas deudas saldría adelante y generaría bonanza. ¿Quién vencerá en esta dualidad? Pues un ejemplo cercano lo tenemos en Irlanda, una economía con problemas puntuales pero que saldría adelante perfectamente si sus bancos no estuviesen en bancarrota. Finalmente éstos arrastran al país al atolladero.


¿Es lo que podemos esperar para nosotros?

"Me gustaría dejar clara que nuestra moneda conjunta está en juego y que tenemos que asumir nuestra responsabilidad (..) si no las consecuencias económicas y sociales "serían incalculables". "Nuestra responsabilidad es enfrentarnos a esta difícil situación", remarcó. Schaeuble recordó que la propia Alemania no está "nadando en dinero", sino más bien "ahogándose en deuda”.



Schaeuble, el ministro de finanzas alemán, quizá sea de los políticos que más demuestra ver de qué va todo cuando hace declaraciones, esto que copio son las últimas. Viene a decir que el euro (y España es su piedra angular) está en peligro y hay que salvarlo, aunque no será Alemania quien ponga todo el dinero. Otras alternativas para revertir este proceso si las cosas se complican son una acción del BCE similar a la Reserva Federal, un tesoro común o algún acuerdo como el de mayo pero más de carácter político y de unión que monetario (ya que nadie querría poner mucho más, unos porque no pueden y otros porque no quieren).

En cualquier caso nosotros tenemos una crisis doble, si EEUU o UK tienen excesiva deuda, nosotros también y además una moneda común que defender. Y lo que es peor, si ahora la perdiésemos la devaluación convertiría en insalvable la carga para muchos, "consecuencias económicas y sociales incalculables" como dice Schaeuble. Siendo el euro algo novedoso y que nos diferencia de lo vivido hace 80 años, si podría "ayudar" en el peor de los casos a vivir una etapa igualmente muy dura.

Pero la crisis no se acaba en Europa ni los paralelismos con la Gran Depresión se acaban aquí, porque si el mundo no se había vuelto suficientemente loco lean el último discurso de Bernanke:


As currently constituted, the international monetary system has a structural flaw (…) This problem is not new. For example, in the somewhat different context of the gold standard in the period prior to the Great Depression (…) Thus, it would be desirable for the global community, over time, to devise an international monetary system that more consistently aligns the interests of individual countries with the interests of the global economy as a whole






Demencial, afirma que el patrón dólar tiene una falla estructural al igual que ocurría con el patrón oro, y que sería deseable ir pensando en cambiarlo. A raíz de esto ya hay quien afirma que al igual que antes, los fallos en el sistema monetario nos llevarán por el camino del proteccionismo. Esperemos que no, pero si ya hemos visto a Bernanke cuestionar el patrón monetario podemos decir que cualquier cosa puede pasar en los próximos años. ¿Una Gran Depresión 2? No, puesto que esta crisis tiene sus propias características y ya estamos viendo que es distinta por ejemplo por la Eurozona o por las políticas llevadas a cabo, pero por desgracia los paralelismos en muchos aspectos son cada día mayores.
 

Fraga II

Madmaxista
Desde
10 Ago 2008
Mensajes
4.511
Reputación
4.179
Lugar
Spanish Great Depression
¿Puede repetir la Fed los errores de la Gran Depresión en los años 30? - Cotizalia.com


¿Puede repetir la Fed los errores de la Gran Depresión en los años 30?





Corren tiempos más que inciertos para Estados Unidos. Han pasado más de cuatro años desde que estalló la crisis financiera y lo cierto es que la primera economía del mundo no despega. Ni lo hace su mercado laboral, ni lo hace la confianza de sus consumidores, ni el sector inmobiliario, ni el manufacturero… Y eso que hasta ahora ha contado con el fuerte apoyo de la Reserva Federal, cuya principal misión es velar por el crecimiento del país.

Este mes se acaba, o así lo contempla a priori en el guión marcado por el regulador, el llamado QE2, o lo que es lo mismo, las medidas de flexibilización cuantitativa que se pusieron en marcha para ayudar a la recuperación del país, y existen serias dudas de que la economía pueda avanzar por su propio pie.

A esto hay que sumar las presiones al alza sobre los precios tras dos años y medio de tipos de interés a cero y en este sentido comienzan a escucharse voces autorizadas alertando del peligro que reside en los bandazos que está dando el sentir de la ciudadanía: si hace un año se temía la deflación, hoy angustia la inflación.

“Es problemático que las preocupaciones públicas sobre la inflación puedan ser tan volátiles”, aseguraba el presidente de la Fed de Philadelphia, Charles Plosser, la semana pasada. “Esto sugiere que podría haber menos credibilidad de la deseable en el compromiso que tiene la Fed con la estabilidad de precios”, explicó en una conferencia del Global Interdependence Center en Finlandia.

Y es que en la confianza en las instituciones está la clave cuando ya existe un debate interno entre los pesos pesados del banco central sobre a qué atenerse en lo que a precios se refiere, a pesar de que la estabilidad de los mismos –como ocurre en Banco Central Europeo- no es de facto su cometido principal.

Inflación subyacente, ¿sí o no?

Mientras que varios economistas defienden que, a diferencia de lo que pasaba en los años ´30, hoy la Fed atiende a la inflación subyacente (sin contar precios de alimentos y energía), y por eso no se va a repetir lo ocurrido en la Gran Depresión, hay algunos como el presidente del regulador de San Louis, James Bullard, apoyan como base sobre la que actuar la inflación general.

Tras el crack de 1929, el regulador era el única que podía haber evitado la caída en cadena de los bancos mediante una inyección masiva de liquidez. Sin embargo, el fuerte repunte de la inflación le llevó a reducir la oferta monetaria y subir los tipos de interés, provocando no sólo la quiebra masiva de entidades, sino también el inicio de un periodo deflacionista y el desplome del consumo.

La sobrerreacción que tuvo en aquel entonces hoy no podría ocurrir en tanto que la institución ahora es capaz de distinguir repuntes ocasionales de las commodities, explica desde la Fed de Nueva York Gauti Eggertsson y que recoge CNNMoney. “Un economista moderno habría identificado que el repunte de los precios en 1936 y 1937 se debía a una subida temporal de las materias primas que no es significativa en la inflación general”.

Sin embargo, no hay que olvidar que Bullard, el mismo que impulsó junto a Ben Bernanke el programa de flexibilización cuantitativa, es de la opinión contraria, y de hecho el mes pasado en un estudio se refirió al IPC subyacente como un “concepto podrido”.

“Es el momento de suavizar el énfasis en la inflación subyacente como camino para interpretar el proceso inflacionista en EEUU”, aseguró el dirigente. Llegados a este punto, aunque Eggertsson defiende que la Fed no va a volver a cometer los errores del pasado, no conviene perder de vista la corriente capitaneada por Bullard que podría hacer entrar a la economía de Estados Unidos en una dinámica muy peligrosa.










Why the Fed will repeat its worst error - Term Sheet


Why the Fed will repeat its worst error

Is the Fed doomed to repeat its most infamous mistake, the 1937 monetary tightening that extended the Great Depression?

The answer is no if you take the Fed's word for it – though it's hard to feel reassured if you happened to keep an eye on one top official over the past year. Recent hawkish comments by St. Louis Fed President James Bullard show the temptation to talk a big game on inflation, whatever the cost.






A recent Fed paper concludes, not exactly surprisingly, that the central bank won't make the same mistakes again. New York Fed economist Gauti Eggertsson contends that while the Fed of the 1930s was apt to overreact to commodity price shocks, nowadays we know how to take the occasional commodity price surge with the appropriate grain of salt.

And what makes us so smart? Eggertsson argues that the key advance over the past 70-plus years is that economists now tend to look beyond jumpy headline inflation numbers to so-called core inflation, which excludes food and energy prices. A glance at core inflation in 1937 would have shown nervous central bankers that the inflation surge they thought they were clamping off was in fact largely a supply shock confined to a few key goods such as corn and copper.

"A modern economist most likely would have identified the price rise in 1936 and 1937 as a temporary upswing in commodity prices that did not signal a significant increase in overall inflation," Eggertsson writes.

Yet some economists nowadays clearly are less modern than Eggertsson imagines. Take Bullard, the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Last month he published a paper calling core inflation "a rotten concept" and urging the Fed to stop paying attention to it.

"It is time to drop the emphasis on core inflation as a meaningful way to interpret the inflation process in the U.S.," he said in a May 18 speech at New York University.

Bullard's comments were notable because he was Ben Bernanke's sidekick in pushing the bond-buying program known as quantitative easing that the Fed adopted late last year. Back then Bullard was an enthusiastic amower of core inflation, judging by a widely cited August presentation that used the phrase not once or twice but seven times.

Why the about-face? Perhaps Bullard wants to show the Fed knows people can't eat iPads for dinner. In an interview, Bullard says he believes the Fed risks losing credibility with the public by ignoring the prices of goods that account for a substantial share of household spending.

"It's damaging to the Fed to talk about core inflation when everyone can see headline inflation is rising," Bullard said last month. "We need to talk about our challenge in terms of headline inflation, not restate it in terms of something else."

Yet as stirring a soundbite as that makes, it is a dangerous bit of grandstanding to be linking policy to the more volatile series (see chart, bottom right) at a time when unemployment is 9.1% and, seemingly, not coming down much any time soon. Yes, food and energy prices are higher, but is that necessarily something tighter money is going to fix? And if so at what cost?

As the Eggertsson paper notes, the Fed's antiestéticarful tightening in 1937 halted a recovery that had taken years to develop and dealt sharp blows to employment and production (see chart, above right). A premature response to the next energy shock could surely do the same to the current economic upturn, as shallow as it now appears.

What's more, for all its bubble-era laxity the Fed has erred on the side of being too tight more recently than 1937. David Beckworth, who teaches economics at Texas State and writes on Fed policy at his Macro and Other Market Musings blog, points to the Federal Open Market Committee meeting that took place Sept. 16, 2008 – the day after the failure of Lehman Brothers and the day the Fed was preparing to make an $85 billion loan to AIG (AIG).





Though all measures of inflation were coming down as summer turned to fall and the economy clearly was slowing amowing a July brush with $4-a-gallon gasoline, the FOMC decided to hold the fed funds rate at 2%, concluding that "the downside risks to growth and the upside risks to inflation are both of significant concern to the committee."

As it turned out, the upside risks to inflation didn't materialize. To the contrary, the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy and the collapse of the shadow banking system exposed the economy to a severe credit shock.

Real interest rates, which subtract inflation from the nominal rate to show the true cost of borrowing, soared as high as 8% in the aftermath, as demand for goods and services evaporated and prices tumbled.

All this because the arm-waving amowing the summer's run to $147-a-barrel crude -- which briefly pushed the headline consumer price index above 5% -- scared the Fed into wanting to look tough on inflation. Sound familiar?

"Effectively they ended up tightening during the crisis – and it was because they were afraid of looking soft on inflation," says Beckworth. "They were lulled by the siren of headline inflation."

Bullard insists that tracking headline inflation rather than core doesn't force the Fed into anything. In mid-2008, he said, the Fed could have stayed on the sideline even with inflation above 5% "by laying out a clear explanation for why headline inflation is high and why you aren't taking immediate action." Doing so, he says, "would free you up to do other things," such as explain what sort of events might lead to policy responses.

In any case, Eggertsson says the Fed won't be lulled again the next time. But watching Bullard play to the hawkish crowd, it's hard to share the researcher's optimism.
 

Pepe Broz

Madmaxista
Desde
31 Mar 2009
Mensajes
4.674
Reputación
7.433
Las bolsas al unisono gritan:

Queremos Q3!! Queremos Q3!!!
 

Fraga II

Madmaxista
Desde
10 Ago 2008
Mensajes
4.511
Reputación
4.179
Lugar
Spanish Great Depression
La Depresión Menor · ELPAÍS.com


TRIBUNA: La crisis del euro - La factura del sector privado PAUL KRUGMAN
La Depresión Menor





Esta es una época interesante, y lo digo en el peor sentido de la palabra. Ahora mismo, estamos viendo no una sino dos crisis inminentes, cada una de las cuales podría provocar un desastre mundial. En Estados Unidos, los fanáticos de derechas del Congreso pueden bloquear un necesario aumento del tope de la deuda, lo que posiblemente haría estragos en los mercados financieros mundiales. Mientras tanto, si el plan que acaban de pactar los jefes de Estado europeos no logra calmar los mercados, podríamos ver un efecto dominó por todo el sur de Europa, lo cual también haría estragos en los mercados financieros mundiales.

Solamente podemos esperar que los políticos congregados en Washington y Bruselas consigan esquivar estas amenazas. Pero hay una pega: aun cuando nos las arreglemos para evitar una catástrofe inmediata, los acuerdos que se están alcanzando a ambos lados del Atlántico van a empeorar la crisis económica casi con toda seguridad.

De hecho, los responsables políticos parecen decididos a perpetuar lo que he dado en llamar la Depresión Menor, el prolongado periodo de paro elevado que empezó con la Gran Recesión de 2007-2009 y que continúa hasta el día de hoy, más de dos años después de que la recesión supuestamente terminase.

Hablemos un momento sobre por qué nuestras economías están (todavía) tan deprimidas. La gran burbuja inmobiliaria de la década pasada, que fue un fenómeno tanto estadounidense como europeo, estuvo acompañada por un enorme aumento de la deuda familiar. Cuando la burbuja estalló, la construcción de viviendas cayó en picado, al igual que el gasto de los consumidores a medida que las familias cargadas de deudas hacían recortes.

Aun así, todo podría haber ido bien si otros importantes actores económicos hubiesen incrementado su gasto y llenado el hueco dejado por el desplome de la vivienda y el retroceso del consumo. Pero ninguno lo hizo. En concreto, las empresas que disponen de capital no ven motivos para invertir ese capital en un momento en el que la demanda de los consumidores es débil.

Los Gobiernos tampoco hicieron demasiado por ayudar. Algunos de ellos -los de los países más débiles de Europa y los Gobiernos estatales y locales de EE UU- se vieron de hecho obligados a recortar drásticamente el gasto ante la caída de los ingresos. Y los comedidos esfuerzos de los Gobiernos más fuertes -incluido, sí, el plan de estímulo de Obama- apenas bastaron, en el mejor de los casos, para compensar esta austeridad forzosa.

Así que tenemos unas economías deprimidas. ¿Qué proponen hacer al respecto los responsables políticos? Menos que nada. La desaparición del paro de la retórica política de la élite y su sustitución por el pánico al déficit han sido verdaderamente llamativas. No es una respuesta a la opinión pública. En un sondeo reciente de CBS News/The New York Times, el 53% de los ciudadanos mencionaba la economía y el empleo como los problemas más importantes a los que nos enfrentamos, mientras que solo el 7% mencionaba el déficit. Tampoco es una respuesta a la presión del mercado. Los tipos de interés de la deuda de EE UU siguen cerca de sus mínimos históricos.

Pero las conversaciones en Washington y Bruselas solo tratan sobre recortes del gasto (y puede que subidas de impuestos, es decir, revisiones). Esto es claramente cierto en el caso de las diversas propuestas que se están tanteando para resolver la crisis del tope de la deuda en Estados Unidos. Pero es igual de cierto en Europa.

El jueves, los "jefes de Estado y de Gobierno de la zona euro y las instituciones de la UE" -este trabalenguas da idea, por sí solo, de lo confuso que se ha vuelto el sistema de gobierno europeo- publicaban su gran declaración. No era tranquilizadora.

Para empezar, resulta difícil creer que la compleja y estrambótica ingeniería financiera que la declaración propone pueda resolver realmente la crisis griega, por no hablar de la crisis europea en general.

Pero, aunque así fuera, ¿qué pasará después? La declaración pide unas drásticas reducciones del déficit "en todos los países salvo en aquellos con un programa" que debe entrar en vigor "antes de 2013 como muy tarde". Dado que esos países "con un programa" se ven obligados a observar una estricta austeridad fiscal, esto equivale a un plan para que toda Europa reduzca drásticamente el gasto al mismo tiempo. Y no hay nada en los datos europeos que indique que el sector privado vaya a estar dispuesto a cargar con el muerto en menos de dos años.

Para aquellos que conocen la historia de la década de 1930, esto resulta demasiado familiar. Si alguna de las actuales negociaciones sobre la deuda fracasa, podríamos estar a punto de revivir 1931, el hundimiento bancario mundial que hizo grande la Gran Depresión. Pero si las negociaciones tienen éxito, estaremos listos para repetir el gran error de 1937: la vuelta prematura a la contracción fiscal que dio al traste con la recuperación económica y garantizó que la depresión se prolongase hasta que la II Guerra Mundial finalmente proporcionó el impulso que la economía necesitaba.

¿He mencionado que el Banco Central Europeo -aunque, afortunadamente, no la Reserva Federal- parece decidido a empeorar aún más las cosas subiendo los tipos de interés?

Hay una antigua cita, atribuida a distintas personas, que siempre me viene a la mente cuando observo la política pública: "No sabes, hijo mío, con qué poca sabiduría se gobierna el mundo". Ahora esa falta de sabiduría se pone plenamente de manifiesto, cuando las élites políticas de ambos lados del Atlántico malogran la respuesta al trauma económico haciendo caso omiso de las lecciones de la historia. Y la Depresión Menor continúa.

Paul Krugman es profesor de Economía en Princeton y premio Nobel 2008. © 2011. New York Times Service. Traducción de News Clips.
 

Thom son

Madmaxista
Desde
25 Nov 2009
Mensajes
17.907
Reputación
27.805
¡Las lecciones de la Historia! No solo la élite política. Hay tanto pánfilo replica-dogmas que se las pasa por el forro demandando las mismas viejas y fracasadas políticas y recurriendo a los mismos viejos errores del pasado que intentan colar, eso sí, como novedosos y, lo que es peor, supuestamente contrastados y exitosos... Eso sí, en la teoría.

Luego, con dos simplezas despachan, por ejemplo, a Krugman.
 

Fraga II

Madmaxista
Desde
10 Ago 2008
Mensajes
4.511
Reputación
4.179
Lugar
Spanish Great Depression
Las cosas por su nombre: ¿se viene una depresión?


Las cosas por su nombre: ¿se viene una depresión?



Ya es casi oficial, la recesión en Europa será prácticamente inevitable en 2012 y, según la canciller alemana Angela Merkel, se trata de una crisis que “durará años”.

Para Paul Krugman, es tiempo de empezar a llamar a las cosas por su nombre, la situación actual se puede describir perfectamente como una depresión. “Cierto, no se trata de un replay de la Gran Depresión, pero esto es un escaso consuelo”, escribió en The New York Times.

El viernes, la directora del FMI, Christine Lagarde, pareció coincidir con el diagnóstico de Krugman. Advirtió que si esta crisis no se ataja con decisión, “las consecuencias podrían llegar a ser similares a las que se atraversaron en la Gran Depresión”.

En cualquier caso, se trata de reacciones a decisiones humanas, no a la acción de fuerzas de la naturaleza. La insistencia de los líderes europeos en imponer políticas de ajuste (como el nuevo paquete que anunció Italia la semana pasada) es el principal factor que está agravando la crisis, dicen los críticos.

El mayor parecido entre esta crisis y la de los años 30 está en las decisiones de gastos . A finales de la década de 1920, el presidente estadounidense Herbert Hoover cometió un error fatal al imponer medidas de austeridad basadas en aumentos de impuestos y recortes presupuestarios.

La economía de EE.UU. se hundió en la recesión. Franklin Roosevelt, su sucesor, comenzó a gastar y entonces se inició una recuperación. Pero después de 1936, el mismo Roosevelt se propuso ajustar el cinturón con medidas de austeridad y la economía se derrumbó nuevamente. El resultado: la actividad económica no volvió a sus niveles previos a 1929 sino hasta después de las enormes oleadas de gasto público que precedieron a la Segunda Guerra Mundial.

Ahora se ha anunciado que habrá una nueva cumbre de dirigentes europeos a finales de enero o principios de febrero para revisar la situación. Pero lo más probable es que esta reunión sirva para evitar la siguiente recesión, no la que está en curso.

El primer síntoma de que los inversionistas prefieren apostar a lo seguro, es decir al dólar, se advirtió esta semana en los mercados de divisas. Por primera vez en 11 meses, el valor del euro contra el dólar se situó por debajo de 1,30. Hay varios analistas que están empezando a pronosticar un valor del euro a la par del dólar en 2012 y posiblemente a 0,85 en 2013. Las economías débiles, sostienen, suelen tener monedas débiles. Y eso, suponiendo que el euro sobrevive a esta segunda recesión, depresión o como se lo quiera llamar. El dólar, está claro, ya no tiene ninguna competencia como moneda mundial de reserva .

Si el euro se devaluara, se abriría un nuevo escenario para la economía argentina, cuya evolución estuvo acompañada en los últimos años por un euro fuerte y su contrapartida, un dólar débil, que permitió retrasar la cotización peso/dólar sin mayores consecuencias sobre la competitividad de las exportaciones.

Uno de los mayores problemas que enfrentó la política económica este año ha sido la salida de divisas (ver página 9). Un eventual derrumbe del euro no resulta ser un buen augurio para el futuro ni del intercambio comercial ni para el nivel de las reservas internacionales. En este marco debería entenderse la decisión de las autoridades de “sentarse” sobre las importaciones y las remesas de ganancias al exterior








Lagarde alerta de una depresión como la de los años 30


Lagarde alerta de que la economía se arriesga a caer en una depresión como la de los años 30
La directora del FMI afirma que "ninguna economía en el mundo, ya sea de ingresos bajos, emergente o superdesarrollada, va a ser inmune a la crisis"



Washington. (EUROPA PRESS).- La falta de colaboración a nivel internacional entre los países representa, desde el punto de vista económico, un riesgo de mayor proteccionismo y aislamiento, tal y como sucedió en los años 30, alertó la directora gerente del Fondo Monetario Internacional (FMI), Christine Lagarde, en un discurso ante el Departamento de Estado de EEUU. Si la comunidad internacional no trabaja de manera conjunta "el riesgo desde el punto de vista económico es de un mayor proteccionismo y aislamiento, tal y como sucedió en los años 30, y lo que vino a continuación es algo que no esperamos", dijo Lagarde.

"Ninguna economía en el mundo, ya sea de ingresos bajos, emergente o superdesarrollada, va a ser inmune a la crisis que, no sólo está desplegándose, sino aumentando su escalada", añadió. En este sentido, la directora del FMI subrayó que la crisis no podrá resolverse por las acciones de un grupo de países, sino que deberá serlo por todos los países y regiones.

Así, Lagarde señaló que incluso las economías emergentes, que sufrieron su propia crisis en los 90, tendrán que colaborar en la lucha contra la crisis, aunque apuntó que el liderazgo en esta ocasión corresponde a Europa. "Va a tener que empezar en el núcleo de la crisis, que obviamente se encuentra en los países europeos y, particularmente, en aquellos que comparten la moneda", dijo la exministra francesa de Finanzas, quien no dudó en reconocer que dicha unión monetaria "no se ha completado de manera apropiada con una unión fiscal y económica sobre la que actualmente se trabaja".